The Sales Tax: History of Its Fallen Champions
The sales tax has a long and fractured history. It doesn’t make sense to repeat it.
May 25, 2016
Mason Gaffney, Ph.D.
Economist

Editor’s note: This is a reprint. Originally published April 2005.

“.. in England the land-tax at this moment produces half a million less than it did a century ago, while the taxes on consumption have experienced an addition of thirteen millions per annum during the same period. This is an attempt... to throw the burthen from the rich upon the poor...”
—William Godwin, 1793, Enquiry Concerning Political Justice

Commercial-capitalist civilization has progressed in step with people’s success in fending off sales taxes in their various guises.  We might begin with The Enlightenment, late 18th Century, with its epicenter in Versailles.  At the core were the philosophes; at their core were les économistes, or Physiocrats; and at their core was the physician from whom they took their name, François Quesnay. One of their main causes was to rid France of its internal sales taxes and replace them with heavier taxes on property, especially land values. (Bowers, 1925; Brinton; Condorcet; De Tocqueville; DuPont; Foner; Gershoy; Greenlaw; Hill; Jupp; Lefebvre; Lodge; Roberts; Sée; Turgot; Whitlock)

Louis XVI named Quesnay’s ally Turgot as his Finance Minister; Turgot energetically set about implementing Physiocratic reforms, which they called laissez-faire.  The major landowners of France, the tax-exempt nobles and clergy, led in resisting.  When Turgot issued an edict abolishing the corvée (forced labor), and substituting a land tax, The Parlement de Paris, representing these landowners, issued a “Rémonstrance” against the Edict.  It urged the King to maintain the rights of property, and also to preserve “rights attached to the person and those which derive from the prerogatives of birth and Estate.”  The Rémonstrance warns against “mixing all the orders of the state together by subjecting them to the uniform yoke of a land tax.”  This would cause “disorder and confusion.”  “It is necessary that some command and others obey.” That was the mindset of sales tax champions then, plainly spoken; today they speak riddles in soothing tones, but to the same end.

The weak-willed Louis caved in and dumped Turgot in 1776, opening a chain of fiscal disasters that led to revolution in 1789, regicide, Red Terror, White Terror, and a bourgeois reaction.  When the dust settled, nobles’ lands were taxed, church lands were sold off, internal sales taxes disappeared, and France’s economy boomed along Quesnay’s lines.  I will not defend Napoleon’s imperialism, but France’s new economy was the base that made it possible.  It spread the new ideas all over Europe.  After the Bourbon Restoration, France never returned to her old fiscal ways.

Quesnay might have learned by looking back on England’s Stuart line of monarchs.  Charles I lost his head in 1649 after pushing sales taxes on his subjects without permission of Parliament (TCE pp. 873, 2124; Leake). The shift from direct land taxes to excise taxes accelerated from 1630-40, especially (Fusfeld). James II later terminated the Stuart family dynasty for good while taking his fiscal advice from Thomas Hobbes (Leviathan) who favored sales taxes.  The Glorious Revolutionists of 1688 instead read and patronized John Locke, of whom Americans know.[1]  But then after a bit came George II and Robert Walpole (“Every man has his price”), 1721-40.  Walpole survived until he tried to tax salt, which brought him down at last (Cobbett; Wyndham; Brisco).  Quesnay might also have looked across the Channel of his own time at George III, who lost the American colonies after imposing taxes on their sugar and tea, along with a battery of other imposts, “The Intolerable Acts” of Lord Grenville (Miller 103).

How easily some people forget history.  Recently, a Massachusetts group invoked the Boston Tea Party to support their campaign against property taxes, which they would replace with more sales taxation.  They were full of the spirit of Sam Adams Beer, perhaps, but not of the man who rebelled against British sales taxes (Miller 103).  

Quesnay might also have looked southwest to Spain.  Adam Smith asked why Spain, jump-started with gold pilfered from the New World, lagged in economic progress.  He laid it on the Spanish alcabala and cientos (Smith, p.850-51; Groves, p.307, n.14; Ustaritz; Rocker). These were heavy sales taxes, often in cascade, that spared the grandees from taxes on their lands while stifling Spanish commerce and industry (Klein).  Under Philip II with his sales taxes, Spain declared national bankruptcy three times.  Adam Smith contrasted Great Britain (pp.851-52), noting that the interior commerce of G.B. is relatively tax free.[2]

“This freedom of interior commerce ... is perhaps one of the principle causes of the prosperity of G.B.; every country being necessarily the best and most extensive mkt for the greater part of the productions of its own industry.”

In the new U.S.A. the Federalists under Hamilton took control, and began levying excise taxes. Things came to a boil in 1794 when farmers of western Pennsylvania rebelled against a tax on their corn (maize, that is), which they concentrated in whiskey to cut down on transportation costs.  Hamilton, who had Napoleonic ambitions, led Federal troops to put down this “whisky rebellion” against his revenuers.  The voters thought him either ridiculous or dangerous, and when they found him dominating the subsequent cabinet of John Adams, of which he was not even a member, and leading the country into the depression of 1798, they retired his party and installed Jefferson, whose Virginia dynasty shaped the nation for the next 36 years. (President J.Q. Adams, 1825-29, had left the Federalists in 1807, supported Madison for President, and been Monroe's Sec. of State.  Andrew Jackson, 1829-37, had allied with French Jean Lafitte to fight the redcoats at New Orleans, and led Jefferson's old Party against the Whigs.)

These Virginians were heavily imbued with Physiocracy. Jefferson, Madison and Monroe had all represented the colonies or the U.S.A. in Paris, as had their friend Franklin, where they hobnobbed with philosophers and picked up their ideas (Bigelow IV:195; Sparks X:300, 345; Van Doren, p.372; Philip Foner pp.15, 24-39). They were pro-French, even as France shifted from monarchy to Directory to Empire.  It was Monroe who had led the fight for the Commerce Clause, freeing internal trade from excise taxes (Norton, p. 51); Jefferson who wrote the Northwest Ordinance and bought Louisiana, and brought the Physiocrats Gallatin and DuPont into his circle, and welcomed Tom Paine back from France, and extended easy credit to small buyers of western lands; and it was Madison, with all his faults, who masterminded the Constitution, and then, in the War of 1812, used the Federal power to tax property, a power he had so carefully circumscribed (Medina).  They got the new nation off to a flying start.

Jefferson Davis had to finance secession with excise taxes.  The Confederate states, even though fighting to survive, stood on their states' rights, and bucked an attempted C.S.A. property tax (Eric Foner, p. 15).  So Davis put a 10% tax on all farm production, paid in kind - a crushing burden on marginal farmers.  Winn Parish, LA, for example, home of Huey Long, in 1863 petitioned General Grant to save them from this "oppression" (Brinkley, p.11; Williams, p.xii).  The C.S.A. repudiated its bonds and currency, and lost the war catastrophically.

In Cuba, Spain imposed high excise taxes on farming and mining, and tariffs favoring Spain. Spain incurred debts on the security of these revenues from Cuba.  Exiled rebel José Martí was in New York when Henry George ran for Mayor, and we may assume absorbed some of the spirit.  He went home to lead a revolt, which he lost in 1895, but which led to Spain’s disastrous war with the U.S. and the loss of Cuba, Puerto Rico, and The Philippines. In the peace treaty, the U.S. repudiated these “odious” debts—a precedent to remember now that we are the world’s leading collection agency (Nevins and Commager, pp.362, 366).

In Russia, Czar Nicholas II lost a war he could not finance from excise taxes.  In 1919 he was shot, with his entire family, and his Romanov dynasty terminated.

Back down home in Indiana, long-time Senator Albert J. Beveridge, Progressive Republican, was presidential timber.  He pressed for a national sales tax, suffered his first loss in 1922, and retired to meditate on his error while writing a biography of Lincoln (Bowers, 1932).  

About the same time, President Warren Harding was calling for a national sales tax (originally, to fund a Vet's Bonus) (Russell, p.534).  Harding's huge majority from 1920 evaporated. Republicans considered dumping him for a 2nd term, but he died in office.  His guru Andrew Mellon remained, however, urging taxing consumption (Greider, p.87).  Mellon was Treasury Secretary under (or was it over?) three presidents, 1921-31. 

In 1932, Herbert Hoover proposed a national sales tax.  By now his Treasury Secretary was Ogden Mills, friend and ally of Professor Richard T. Ely, another sales-taxer and professional anti-Georgist.  Mellon, Mills and Ely helped make Herbert Hoover the most beatable president in U.S. history.  Democrats ran against his memory for several terms after that, and generally won on a pro-consumption platform. 

Anyone the Democrats nominated would have won in 1932. The fallback nominee, Newton D. Baker, had a strong single tax background as the protégé and successor of Tom L. Johnson in Cleveland.  Wm. Randolph Hearst, of all people, swung the 1932 convention to FDR, whom he disliked intensely, just to block Baker (Cramer, p.253).  A Georgist came that close to the top, and most people haven’t even known it! It may be relevant that Hearst, like Mills, was a major California landowner.[3] Hearst’s garish castle at San Simeon still sits amid 82,000 unused acres, including many miles of prime coastline, and coastal hills with seaviews to kill for.

Hoover's ally in 1932 was Senator Joseph Robinson of Arkansas. Robinson was leader of the Senate Democrats, but jumped ship to join Hoover pushing a sales tax (cf. nominal Democrat Gary Condit, discussed below).  Huey Long of Louisiana soon invaded Robinson's home state to humiliate him by winning a Senate seat for unknown Hattie Carraway, breaking Robinson's power and making Long a national power (Brinkley, p.43).

In 1930 Gandhi led his march to the sea in India, protesting a British salt tax.  In 1947 the Brits finally pulled out.  They had beaten Germany, Italy and Japan, but lost to unarmed Indians, led by a scrawny half-naked pacifist and Luddite protesting a sales tax on salt.

In 1948, Chiang Kai-shek and his Kuomintang were driven from China by Communists under Mao Tse-tung.  Chiang had tried to finance his government with excise taxes and inflation (Seagrave, pp.188-92, 313-21, et passim).  Once settled in Taiwan, with his back to the wall, Chiang finally turned to land reform and land taxation as taught by his early mentor, the sainted Sun Yat-sen (Chang).  These policies quickly helped turned Taiwan from a 3rd-World backwater into a sparkling economic success story (King; Riew; Lin).

From 1960-65, the Government of South Viet Nam doubled its sales tax from 10% to 20%, under prodding from U.S. "experts" (Sapiro).  Thus they ruined their nation's commerce, while big landowners were untaxed.  The V.C. lined up against them and won peasant support.  The rest is history.

Back in the U.S.A., in 1980 Oregon Congressman Al Ullman, head of U.S. House Committee on Ways and Means, started pressing for a VAT from his national eminence.  Voters of his district around Bend, in Harney County, promptly retired him, sacrificing all the local pork that comes from having a powerful senior Congressman.  Ullman changed his position at the 11th hour but Republican Denny Smith hung the sales tax albatross on Ullman, and won. (TIME, 6 Oct 1980; McIntyre, p.13).[4]

The catchword of 1988 was “austerity,” meaning we should tax consumption, to aid capital formation (Greider, p.82).[5]  Pete Peterson's Atlantic article was most influential (10/87).  Economist Larry Summers, advising Dukakis, took this line.  I doubt if his famous uncles, Paul Samuelson and Kenneth Arrow, agreed, but all they have is Nobel Laureates. Dukakis lost and disappeared.  Harvard’s Corporation later picked Summers for President of their University, the richest in the world, with vast holdings of real estate in its endowment.  George Bush, contesting Dukakis, promised "no new taxes," which to some might mean no sales tax.  Soon, VAT advocates rose to high positions under Bush, so voters might have turned to Clinton in 1992 to keep people of that mindset out of power. That was, at any rate, the outcome, good for two terms.

In 1989 the Japanese made Sosuke Uno Prime Minister.  He introduced the first Japanese sales tax.  He also flaunted his mistress.  The housewives of Japan turned him out for both reasons, probably in the order given (contemporary news reports).  He lasted only 69 days, a record for brevity (Kita). Now, visiting Japanese economists affect never to have heard of him.

In 1993 Canada, PM Brian Mulroney punched through a national sales tax. Mulroney had held power for nine years, but in May, 1993, polls showed him to be the most unpopular Prime Minister in Canadian history.  He resigned and gave the hot seat to young Kim Campbell of Vancouver. Later in 1993 Ms. Campbell and her "Progressive Conservative" Party lost so thoroughly that they went from the governing party to a minority too small to be official any more (current press reports).

Chrétien won by vowing to get rid of GST.  However, he hasn't actually done so.  Once this camel's nose gets under the tent, it's hard to eject it.

In Feb 1994 Japanese PM Morihiro Hosokawa announced an income tax cut, to be replaced by raising the sales tax, which he called the "people's welfare tax," from 3% to 7%, three years in the future (BW,16 AUG 93, p.47).  He and U.S. Treasury Sec’y Lloyd Bentsen touted this as a tax cut (LAT 3 Feb 94).  In a stunning reversal, Hosokawa backed down in just a few days, to keep the Socialists on board. They say he had been drunk with his high approval ratings, and sneaky in his euphemisms (LAT 4 Feb 94, p.1).  Any resemblance between this episode and current events in the U.S.A. is purely coincidental.  

In Venezuela, 1989-1993, Carlos Andres Perez pushed privatization, IMF, and VAT, a package known as “Latin neo-liberalism.” He also ran a deficit.  The inflation rate was 45%. In 1994 Venezuela elected Rafael Caldera, who campaigned against all that.  Caldera called for revoking a national sales tax, but won with only a plurality and not enough strength to accomplish much (LAT 3 Feb 94 A6).  The sales tax was "seen by many (IMF) economists as essential to recovery.”  So now we have Hugo Chavez, and thank you, IMF.

In 2000 U.S. Rep. Tom Campbell (R-Cal) ran for the U.S. Senate.  Campbell has a doctorate in economics from Chicago, and is also a law professor at Stanford. He proposed a flat 20% sales tax, to end the income tax.  Bill Archer (R-Tx), Chair of Ways and Means, had a similar proposal; but Campbell would exempt food, medicine, and "the cost of housing up to an average in a given area" (LAT 9 Dec 99 A3).  Fresh-faced Campbell lost badly to Diane Feinstein, but soon entered the Valhalla of failed candidates: he is now California State Director of Finance, under Gov. Schwarzenegger.  Who knows what new surprises they are cooking up.

In 2002 voters in and around Modesto retired Cong. Gary Condit.  Democrat Condit had lined up with Republican Congressmen Dick Armey and Bill Archer, Senators Richard Lugar and Philip Gramm, Presidential Candidate Stephen Forbes, and other sales-taxers to push for a national sales tax. Condit was accused in a sex scandal, which may have helped beat him.  However, many other politicians, like Cong. Kenneth Calvert and Henry Hyde, Presidents George Washington, Thomas Jefferson, Grover Cleveland, Warren Harding, Franklin Roosevelt, Dwight Eisenhower, John F. Kennedy, Bill Clinton, and others have survived sex scandals, while Mayor Rudy Giuliani of New York City, who moved his mistress right into Gracie Mansion, is even now considered prime presidential timber by the very Party of Bill Bennett, Pat Robertson, James Dobson, and other ideologues of personal religiosity.

In March, 2000, Richard Riordan, candidate for Governor of California, lost the Republican primary to Bill Simon, a weak candidate who then lost to Gray Davis.  Riordan, the early favorite, made many mistakes, but one of them was retaining Michael Boskin as his economic advisor, helping alienate whatever liberal Republican support he might have garnered.  Boskin of the Hoover Institution is a sales-taxer of the Bill Archer-Steve Forbes genre.

The upshot seems to be that sales taxes have been instruments of tyranny, voters do not like them, they stifle commerce and industry and their own base, and they lead to national bankruptcy.  We will point up many more faults, in the next issue.  Champions keep entering the field because those with an overplus of taxable property keep financing them.  For most of us, though, the sales tax is a dumb, noxious idea.

Footnotes

  1. Locke’s egalitarian views on the concentration of wealth are cited in Jupp, p.xvi.  "The due measure of property is set by Nature, which limits the am't of labor which a man can perform, and the length of time the products of the earth can be used before they decay.  Thus restricted, it is lawful to take as much as a man can make use of to any advantage in life before it spoils, and make it his property.  Anything beyond this is more than his share, and belongs to others." [Locke, par. 31].
    p.xviii, "What portion a man carved for himself was easily seen, and it was useless, as well as dishonest, to carve himself too much, or take more than he needed." [par. 51].
    Thorstein Veblen followed these ideas closely, especially in his Absentee Ownership, 1923.
  2. ‍“Relatively” is a necessary word.  Godwin the idealist 20 years later deplored the growth of taxes on “consumption” (read retail trade). The glass that Smith saw as half full, Godwin saw as half empty.
  3. The extensive and intricate Mills family relations with major robber barons of early California are sketched out in Brechin, pp. 38, 54-55, 89, 98, 218, 349, et passim.  Mills’ grandfather moved to New York where he and his offspring entered into top publishing, financial, real estate, and patroon circles.
  4. ‍Correspondence between Ullman and Emile Woolf was instrumental in turning Ullman around.  Woolf is an English accountant and a Georgist.
  5. ‍Thus, Hatsopoulos, Poterba and Krugman, Overconsumption, was in that fashion.

Bibliography

Barnes, Peter, 2001. Who Owns the Sky? Washington, Covelo, London: Island Press

Beard, Charles A.,  1936.  An Ec. Interpretation of the Constitution of the U.S.  NY: Macmillan

Beveridge, Albert J.  1928.  Abraham Lincoln.  Vols.  I, II, separately paged.  Cambridge: Houghton Mifflin Co.

Bigelow, John, (ed.) 1868. Autobiography of Benjamin Franklin. Philadelphia: J.B. Lippincott; London: Trübner & Co.

Brisco, Norris.A., 1907.  The Economic Policy of Robert Walpole. NY: Columbia Univ. Press

Bogart, Ernest L.  1936.  Economic History of the American People.  NY: Longmans, Green and Co.  2nd ed.

Bowden, Witt, Michael Karpovich and Abbott P.  Usher, 1937.  An Economic History of Europe since 1750.  NY: American Book Co.

Bowers, Claude G.  1925.  Jefferson and Hamilton.  Boston and New York: Houghton Mifflin Company.

Bowers, Claude G.  1932.  Beveridge and the Progressive Era.  Cambridge: Houghton Mifflin Co.

Bowers, Claude G.  1936.  Jefferson in Power.  Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company. 

Bowers, Claude G.  1945.  The Young Jefferson.  Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.

Bowers, Claude G.  1929.  The Tragic Era: the Revolution after Lincoln.  Cambridge: Houghton Mifflin Company.

Brechin, Gray, 1999.  Imperial San Francisco.  Berkeley and Los Angeles: Univ. of Calif. Press

Brinkley, Alan, 1982.  Voices of Protest.  Huey Long, Father Coughlin, and the Great Depression.  NY: Alfred A. Knopf

Brinton, Crane, 1934.  A Decade of Revolution. New York: Harper and Row, Publishers, Inc. (1963, Harper Torchbook Ed., New York, Evanston, and London

Bryce, James, 1891. The American Commonwealth. London: Macmillan and Co. 2nd Edition Revised. Vols. I, II.

Burne, Jerome (ed,) 1989.  Chronicle of the World.  Longman Group UK  Ltd., London.  Cited as "Chron".

Carstensen, Vernon (ed.) 1962.  The Public Lands.  Madison: UW Press.

Chang, David, 1987.  “Doctrines of Sun Yat-sen.”  MS, Oshkosh State University, Wisconsin

CHW, Columbia History of the World.

Cobbett, William, 1806-20.  The Parliamentary History of England.  London: Longmans et al. (Re Sir Wm. Wyndham.)

Cole, ArthurH.  1927.  "Cyclical and Sectional Variations in the Sale of Public Lands, 1816-60."  RES 9:41-53.  Reprinted in Vernon Carstensen, 1962:229-52.  

Coles, Jr., Harry 1957.  "Applicability of the Public Land System to La."  Miss.  Val.  Hist.  Rev.  1957:39-58.  Rpt. Carstensen (ed.) 1962:207-27.

Condorcet, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas, 1786.  Vie de M. Turgot London: 1786

Constitution of the U.S., Article I, Sect. 8

Cramer, Clarence H., 1961.  Newton D. Baker, A Biography.  Cleveland and NY: The World Publishing Company.

De Tocqueville, Alexis, 1856.  Stuart Gilbert transl. from 1858 French ed. The Old Regime and the French Revolution.  Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday and Company, Inc., 1955

DuPont de Nemours, Pierre Samuel, 1782. Mémoires sur la Vie et les ouvrages de M. Turgot. Paris: Barrois la Dîné

Foner, Eric 1988, Reconstruction. NY: Harper and Row

Foner, Philip, 1948, 1974,  Introduction to Thomas Paine, The Age of Reason, Secaucus, NJ: Citadel Press,

Fusfeld, Daniel, June, 1960.  Telephone interview for quotation in House and Home Magazine

Gaffney, Mason, 2000. “More on Clarifying Sales Tax History. a response to John Mikesell.” State Tax Notes, April 3, 2000

Gaffney, Mason, 2000. “Why Sales Taxes?” State Tax Notes, February 14, 2000, pp.529-31

Gates, Paul, 1936.  "The Homestead Act in an Incongruous Land System."  Am.  Hist.  Rev.  41:652-81.  Rpt.  Carstensen (ed.) 1962:315-48.

Gershoy, Leo, 1964. The French Revolution and Napoleon.  NY: Appleton-Century-Crofts.

Godwin, William, 1793.  Enquiry Concerning Political Justice.  London: Print for G.G.J. and J. Robinson

Goodrich, Carter, 1960.  Government Promotion of American Canals and Railroads, 1800-1890.  NY: Columbia Univ.  Press.

Greenlaw, RalphW., (ed), 1958.  The Economic Origins of the French Revolution.  Boston: Heath and Co.

Greider, William, 1992.  Who will Tell the People? NY: Simon and Schuster.

Groves, Harold, 1946,  Financing Government, rev. 1946,  New York: H. Holt and Co., p.309).  

Groves, Harold, 1974.  Tax Philosophers.  Ed.  Donald M.  Curran.  Madison: U of Wis.  Press.

Haig, R.M., and Carl Shoup, 1934, The Sales Tax in the American States.  New York: Columbia University Press

Hibbard, Benjamin, 1924.  History of the Public Land Policies. NY: Macmillan

Hill, Malcolm, 1999.  Statesman of  the Enlightenment: the Life of Anne-Robert Turgot.  London: Othila Press

Jupp, Kenneth, 1999.  Introduction to Turgot, q.v.

King, Wei-Shin, 1988. "Land Value Taxation in Taiwan.” Paper distributed and delivered at International Seminar on Real Property and Land as Tax Base for Development, sponsored by Land Reform Training Institute and Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Taoyuan, Republic of China, November 1988, pp. 1-25, xeroxed, at pp. 9-10. Data cited are from Yearbook of Financial Statistics of the Republic of China, MOF. King's paper published as a chapter in the conference Proceedings, edited by Isaac Ofori.

Kita, Mayumi, 1997, email to M. Gaffney, sent at request of William Totten, April 21

Klein, Julius, 1920.  The Mesta.  Cambridge: Harvard Univ. Press

Leake, Chauncey,  1960.  Science News Letter , 17 Feb p.136

Lefebvre, Georges, 1939, The Coming of the French Revolution. R.R. Palmer, transl. Copyright 1957 by Princeton Univ. Press. Vintage Books, 1958.

Lin, Sein, 1978-95, many oral communications

Lodge, Eleanor C., 1931.  Sully, Colbert and Turgot. London: Methuen and co.

McMaster, John Bach, 1891.  A History of the People of the U.S., Vol. III.  NY: D. Appleton and Company (McMaster was with the Wharton School, U of Pa.)

Medina, Harold (former judge, Atty. with Swaine, Cravath and Moore, NY), 1960.  A written legal opinion for P.I. Prentice, of TIME, Inc.  Copies on file.

Miller, William, 1958.  A New History of the United States.  New York: George Braziller, Inc.  

NCE, New Columbia Encyclopedia, 1975.  4th Ed. of The Columbia Encyclopedia.  NY: Columbia Univ. Press

Nelson, Carl, Gladys Blakey and Roy Blakey, 1935. Sales Taxes.  Minneapolis: League of Minnesota Cities.

Nevins, Allan, and Henry S. Commager, 1992 (orig. 1942).  A Pocket History of the United States.  9th Revised Ed.  NY: Pocket Books

Norton, Thomas J., 1940.  The Constitution of the United States.  Cleveland, New York: The World Publishing Co.

O'Callaghan, Jerry, 1954.  "The War Veteran and the Public Lands."  Agric.  Hist.  28:163-68.  Rpt.  Carstensen, 1962:109-19.  

Peterson, Pete, 1987.  “The Morning After.”  The Atlantic Monthly, October

Riew, John, ca. 1980 ff., several articles on Taiwan, available from the author, Department of Economics, Penna. State University, University Park, PA

Roberts, J.M., 1978.  2nd Ed., 1997. The French Revolution. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press

Rothbard, Murray.N., 1962.  The Panic of 1819.  NY: Columbia UP.

Russell, Francis, 1968.  The Shadow of Blooming Grove: Warren G. Harding and His Times.  NY: McGraw-Hill Book Co.

Sakolski, Aaron M., 1932.  The Great American Land Bubble.  NY: Harper and Bros.  (Rpt. 1966, Wm. N. Parker, Gen. Ed., NY: Johnson Reprint Corp.)

Sapiro, Stanley, 199x.  “Insights.”

Schelle, Gustave, 1913-23, Oeuvres de Turgot, vol. ii.  Paris: F. Alcan, p.573

Seagrave, Sterling, 1985.  The Soong Dynasty.  New York etc.: Harper & Row Publishers

See, Henri, 1927, 1931. Economic and Social Conditions in France During the 18th Century.  Trans. E.H. Zeydel. NY: Crofts

See, Henri, 1948.  Histoire Economique de la France.  Librairie Armand Colin, Paris.

See, Henri, 1921. Esquisse d'une Histoire du Regime Agraire en Europe aux 18e et 19e Siecles. Paris: F. Alcan

Sparks, Jared, 1840-47.  The Works of Benj Franklin. Boston: C. Tappan  

TCE, The Columbia Encyclopedia, 5th Ed., 1993.  Chernow, Barbara, and George Vallasi eds.  NY: Columbia Univ. Press

Turgot, Anne-Robert, The Formation and Distribution of Wealth.  Jupp, Kenneth, transl and ed., 1999.  London: Othila Press

Van Doren, Carl, 1938.  Benjamin Franklin.  NY: The Viking Press. 

Whitlock, Brand, 1929.  La Fayette. Vol. I.  NY: D.  Appleton and Co.  

Williams, T. Harry, 1964.  “Introduction” to Huey Long, Autobiography, orig. 1933.  Rpt. 1996, New York: Da Capo Press.  Williams’ “Introduction” orig. 1964.

Wyndham, Sir William, 1739. A letter from an absented member to a friend at Westminster : shewing his reasons for retiring into the country upon the present situation of the affairs of Great Britain.  London: Printed for J. Standen.

Find Out More.
Inside information on economics, society, nature, and technology.
Mason Gaffney, Ph.D.
Economist

MASON GAFFNEY first read about the economist Henry George when a high school junior. After he served in the Pacific during WW II, this interest led him back to get a Ph.D. in Economics at Berkeley, where he tried to meet his teachers’ skepticism and apathy with a dissertation, Land Speculation as an Obstacle to Ideal Allocation of Land. Since then he has published many books and articles on land use, economics, taxation, and public policy. He has been a Professor of Economics at several Universities; a journalist with TIME, Inc.; a researcher with Resources for the Future, Inc.; the head of the British Columbia Institute for Economic Policy Analysis, which he founded; an economic consultant to several businesses and government agencies; and a frequent speaker on economic topics, domestic and foreign, and in political campaigns. He has been Professor of Economics at U.C. Riverside from 1976 through the end of his life. Mason passed in the summer of 2020 and will be lovingly remembered and greatly missed by many. For more information, visit his website at MasonGaffney.org